[P2P-F] Fwd: [Networkedlabour] Future Scenarios for a Collaborative Economy
Michel Bauwens
michel at p2pfoundation.net
Tue Dec 30 06:00:04 CET 2014
recommended critical review of our book, 'Network Society':
---------- Forwarded message ----------
From: Brian Holmes <bhcontinentaldrift at gmail.com>
Date: Tue, Dec 30, 2014 at 11:14 AM
Subject: [Networkedlabour] Future Scenarios for a Collaborative Economy
To: networkedlabour at lists.contrast.org
*Orsan wrote:
global political economy theory started with Cox, and p2p theory would
> benefit from a fruitful exchange. Potentially a p2p update on the
> understanding of the 'transnationalization of production', which as
> process overlaps with the informatization of economy, networkisation of
> societies, and neoliberal globalisation offensive, or vice versa; a
> global political economy upgrade for p2p theory, in my opinion is
> necessary.
>
I totally agree, and that's the thrust of a response I just wrote on
Nettime to the book by Michel Bauwens and Vasilis Kostakis (I'll paste that
response below). One of Cox's followers, Stephen Gill, showed long ago that
neoliberalism has from the outset been a fundamentally trilateral hegemony
(US-Western Europe-Japan). Now that all three poles of the hegemony are
arguably in decline, it would be useful to analyze the weak points where an
amplified and generalized p2p strategy could begin changing the common
sense of citizenship, business and government, and of dissent and
revolution too. I don't do that here - far from it - but the strong
proposals at the end of the Future Scenarios book did seem to call out for
exactly that kind of analysis, which would ground them in reality without
invalidating them by any means. So I hope my critiques of the book do
appear as constructive, because they were intended that way. - best, BH
* * *
http://p2pfoundation.net/Network_Society_and_Future_
Scenarios_for_a_Collaborative_Economy
Thanks for this book, Michel and Vasilis. "Future Scenarios for a
Collaborative Economy" is exceedingly timely and I would recommend it to
anyone interested in the Commons specifically, or in political economy
more generally. In response, I've written something in between a review
and a letter to the authors. I address Michel because he posted it.
Hopefully he will respond to a few of my comments!
I like the book, Michel, but I must also say, I'm somewhat mystified by
it. I like the very sophisticated strategy that it sets out at the end
for a possible transition to a society of commons-based production. I'm
mystified by the rather simplistic presentation of contemporary
capitalism at the beginning. What explains the gap?
In Part I you adopt the theoretical framework of "long waves of
capitalist development" as put forth by Kondratiev and Schumpeter, and
more recently, by Freeman and Perez (Trotsky and Mandel aren't
mentioned). In its most general form, the long-wave idea is that
capitalist society periodically goes through major depressions, during
which investment is withdrawn from production. Meanwhile inventions
accumulate until such time as conditions look good, and a massive wave
of technological investment lays the foundations for a new growth cycle.
Right now we're in such a depression. Therefore you try to analyze the
possible futures of the current "techno-economic paradigm."
There is some ambiguity here, but that's OK. On the one hand the book
follows Carlota Perez, explaining that the information technology
paradigm has run up against a set of internal contradictions and that a
mature phase of sustained growth can only come under new political and
institutional arrangements. On the other hand it hints in certain places
at the emergence, in the upcoming years or decades, of an entirely new
paradigm (which, according to Schumpeter or Freeman, implies a distinct
set of technologies and organizational forms). And then near the end it
quite strongly claims, with Marx, that capitalism must now be overcome
in favor of a different system. The upshot seems to be that the new
society will emerge from the old, perhaps not entirely smoothly, but not
through an apocalyptic rupture either. That's realistic and desirable,
in my view.
I too think some kind of new growth wave is almost inevitable, within a
decade or so - and though it will probably not be on anywhere near so
intensive as the postwar growth wave that so many theorists take as a
norm, it could well be more extensive, reaching far more people on our
densely populated planet. I also think such a new long wave does imply
distinctly new technologies capable of attracting new investment; but in
the absence of radical breakthroughs, the big difference is most likely
to be in the political and institutional structures that govern those
technologies. In other words, the current technology set is more likely
to be augmented and institutionally inflected (as early mass
manufacturing was by postwar Keynesian Fordism) than it is to be
radically transformed (as Keynesian Fordism was radiclly transformed by
the IT revolution). In other words, we are likely to get an extension
and amplification of the certain aspects of the current paradigm, but
under new institutional arrangements.
The problem is, Michel, you never really discuss the current
techno-economic paradigm in any serious way. What you and your co-author
are talking about, in Parts I and II, is a small though important field
of activity, the one that can be identified with keywords such as P2P,
social media, crowd-sourcing, sharing economy, etc. The best parts of
the book contain significant insight into these activities, as one would
expect. However, by claiming to discuss the future of the entire
capitalist system and then not really doing so, you blur the issue and
diminish the potential value of your work.
One can follow Manuel Castells and call the current techno-economic
paradigm "Informationalism" - or better, "Neoliberal Informationalism,"
to give some idea of how this mode of production is governed. But
Informationalism does not mean that the only significant commodity on
the contemporary market is information. Nor does it signal an eclipse of
industry, as you suggest in chapter 1. Instead, Neoliberal
Informationalism has been based on a "lead technology" which is new kind
of producer goods, namely IT in all its facets (computers, software,
cables, mobile telephony, communications satellites, etc). These goods
in combination with networked organizational forms are used to create
transnational supply chains, constituting what is generally called
"just-in-time production" or "the global factory." The characteristic
companies of neoliberal informationalism are not Facebook and Google, as
one would gather from your book, nor even less, recent start-ups like
AirBnB or Uber. They are giant networked firms like WalMart and Apple,
which have their products manufactured in China, coordinate their work
forces and supply chains through sophisticated IT systems, and sell
their wares on the web as well as in the store. Or they are specialized
corporations like Cisco, Verizon and IBM, which furnish the hardware and
software for the new mode of production, distribution and sales. All
these corporations have evolved under the anti-welfare policy mix of
neoliberalism, and with the resources allocated by speculative finance,
which has largely replaced the central planning of national governments.
Not coincidentally, finance itself is crucially enabled by IT.
Computers, cable and satellite networks, transnationalism and financial
governance are key aspects of the current techno-economic paradigm.
Now, it's necessary to add that older sectors, such as petroleum, steel,
chemicals, automobiles, engineering, grain production, etc, remain
tremendously significant for the global economy. They are not just going
to disappear in the next ten or twenty years. However, the way these
sectors are articulated, both internally and between each other, has
effectively been transformed by IT, and that's why we can speak of
Neoliberal Informationalism as a distinct techno-economic paradigm. As
you and Vasilis point out, this paradigm has been predicated on low-wage
precarious labor, and it has called on finance to furnish the means of
consumption through the extension of credit to individuals. The debt
burden of the working and middle classes has risen tremendously and now,
in the overdeveloped world at least, these classes can no longer consume
enough to prop up economic growth. So the system is in a deep crisis,
one which cannot be resolved by simply pumping money into asset markets
as various governments have been doing. That crisis is further
intensified by geopolitical factors (rise of Asia) and by climate change
(which has been made a lot worse by the rise of Asia). How will the
global political economy reconfigure itself under these circumstances?
And what can civil society do to influence the next redeployment of
capital? That's what we need to know.
In Part II, it's really interesting how you present a diagrammatic field
of four distinct yet neighboring scenarios, divided on the one hand
between distributed and centralized organization (or local and global
scales), and on the other hand, between capitalist and commons-based
development paths (or "for profit" and "for benefit" activities, as you
also say). However, for the reasons already stated, the capitalist or
for-profit side of the diagram is not very convincing. In chapters 4 and
5 we are introduced to two supposedly emergent categories. First, a
corporate-scale "netarchical capitalism" where sharing and cooperative
production are enabled by interfaces with closed, privately controlled
backends that facilitate the harvesting of monetary value from social
interaction. And second, an individual-scale "distributed capitalism"
where everyone is asked to become a networked entrepreneur of him- or
herself, creating their own backends for profit. Now, without a doubt
these are already both realities. The first has already undergone
significant expansion, partially wiping out the old media sphere with
some inroads on the hobby, transport, in-person service and vacation
sectors. The second has all the reality of neoliberal ideology: it is
the computerized version of the entrepreneurial ideal, where everyone
freely competes in an open, unregulated economic realm. But the claim
that these figures represent the capitalism of tomorrow could only hold
true if "we are not talking about monopoly capitalism" - which is a
crucial caveat that you supply early on.
The problem is that we are talking about exactly that, Michel, just look
around you. The great oligopolies that corral major sectors of the world
economy, fixing prices and blocking the entry of smaller actors, are
alive and despicably well in every major economic sector, including IT;
and they are supported by very solid forces of the national and
transnational state. To suggest that monopoly capitalism is on the way
out through some force of networked nature is just plain mystifying, and
that's the principal argument I have with this book.
Something else really is changing, though; and this is where the book's
proposals, and more generally, those collected by the P2P Foundation
over the last decade, are really worth one's attention. What's happening
is an impoverishment of the former "First World," which is losing out to
the newly developed countries at the same time as it starts being
subjected to the environmental stresses of climate change. What one can
see on the horizon is a gradual evening-out of global wages, leaving
much of the former West in decaying housing with legacy appliances and
amenities, while populations in the East and South rise up to a roughly
similar level and then stagnate. That's already happening: and the
frustration it engenders was behind the wave of protests in 2011-2013,
whether in Egypt, Brazil, Russia and Turkey, or in Spain and the US. It
is precisely the existence of the oligopolies and the financial elites
(the famous 1%) that account for this dynamic. And we're likely to see
even more intense frustration and anger as these populations have to
confront the difficulties of climate change. Under these conditions,
both newly unemployed people and those who have gained or retained a
precarious hold on middle-class status are likely to find great
attraction in what the book calls "resilient communities" and "global
commons." Additionally, intellectuals with a capacity to see the
dead-end future, whatever their class, will start to look for serious
alternatives.
The discussion becomes tremendously interesting when the "for benefit"
categories are discussed, in their local and global forms. This is the
Marxian part of the book, where a change of the system itself starts to
look desirable. Both the for-benefit categories are based on the
generative matrix of the Commons, and I love the clarity with which
you've expressed its basic principles: "It could be said that every
Commons scheme basically has four interlinked components: a resource
(material and/or immaterial; replenishable and/or depletable); the
community which shares it (the users, administrators, producers and/or
providers); the use value created through the social reproduction or
preservation of these common goods; and the rules and the participatory
property regimes that govern people's access to it."
At this point (Part III), the strict focus on information production is
abandoned and what comes to the fore are the new possibilities presented
by the maker revolution: not only 3-D printing, but all the
computer-controlled tools which can use freely circulated open-source
designs to create practical objects ranging from housing to automobiles.
One can easily see the relevance of such productive capacities for
impoverished communities, especially when they are beset by the stresses
of changing climates, violent storms and soon, rising water levels.
What's more, to take a page from Jeremy Rifkin's recent books, it
becomes clear that with falling costs for solar and wind generation,
energy production itself could potentially be decentralized and managed
according to commons principles so as to build resilient communities.
The combination of alternative energy sources with micro-manufacturing
techniques represents a possible basis for a new form of economic growth
that could cater to very large numbers of people despite, or rather
because of, their inability to reach Fordist and Neoliberal levels of
grotesque hyperconsumption. If the development of capitalist production
during the next upswing could be influenced so as to furnish the
infrastructure and toolkits of decentralized energy production and
micro-manufacturing, then the next wave of growth could have many
positive consequences. That's the paradigm shift that we need, and Part
III makes that quite clear, bravo. The question is, how to make it
happen? What are the "new institutional arrangements" that we need, and
how to achieve them? Or as you and Vasilis write:
"Arguably, the issue is not to produce and consume less per se, but to
develop new models of production which will work on a higher level than
capitalist models. We consider it difficult to challenge the dominant
system if we lack a working plan to transcend it. A post-capitalist
world is bound to entail more than a mere reversal to pre-industrial
times. As the TEPS theory informs us [ie, the theory of techno-economic
paradigm shifts], the adaptation of current institutions and the
creation of new ones take place in the deployment phase of each TEP. We
claim that the times are, finally, mature enough to introduce a radical
political agenda with brand new institutions, fueled by the spirit of
the Commons and aiming to provide a viable global alternative to the
capitalist paradigm beyond degrowth or antiglobalization rhetorics."
Now, that's not Carlota Perez talking anymore. That's a utopian Marxist
strain that has affinities with Italian Autonomia, to the extent it
believes that progressive use-values slumber within the technologies of
capitalist exchange, and that these use-values can be liberated through
the kinds of self-organization that the Internet facilitates. The
question is, how to avoid making this a purely utopian thinking, as
Autonomia has proven to be so far? How can commons-based peer production
reach deeply into daily life? And how can it expand globally, both as a
philosophy and as a set of informational tools that can take full
advantage of the new decentralized energy and manufacturing toolkits?
Or, to put it in strategic terms: How can civil-society actors find the
opportunity, in the current depression and in the upswing that will
almost inevitably follow it, to push corporate production into supplying
the toolkits for a society that will finally escape the worst and most
life-threatening consequences of the capitalist system?
In chapter 8, I feel that you are groping for a way to bridge the gap
between two rather different things. First, the many specific
micro-examples of (mainly informational) commons-based production that
you do provide, in welcome detail. Second, a full-fledged economic
praxis that could rival with the existing forms of Neoliberal
Informationalism, which you (and the rest of us) can only imagine
somewhat fuzzily. The way you approach this problem suggests that you do
recognize the difficulties of overcoming the norms imposed by monopoly
capitalism: after all, they are exemplified by the trajectory of Free
and Open-Source Software, which has still not been broadly adopted even
though the operating systems are now perfectly serviceable and perfectly
free. You cite two very promising projects from what could become the
next techno-economic paradigm, namely the Rep-Rap 3-D printer project
and the Wikispeed automobile project, both of which are impressive and
point the way toward a new articulation of social production. But it's
clear that without support from either large social movements, or
powerful economic actors, or more likely both, a new wave of capitalist
growth will render these projects insignificant - or at least, no more
significant than Free Software is currently. Traditional monopoly
capital will put the breaks on Wikispeed. The coming wave of investment
and development has to be bent to fit collaborative priorities.
Otherwise, a no-future scenario looms.
It is in this context that you introduce the "Partner State Approach":
"The PSA could be considered a cluster of policies and ideas whose
fundamental mission is to empower direct social-value creation, and to
focus on the protection of the Commons sphere as well as on the
promotion of sustainable models of entrepreneurship and participatory
politics." This is absolutely true: commons-based production requires
infrastructure investments that commoners themselves cannot provide, at
least, not as individuals or a members of small and fractious voluntary
networks. The implication (which I don't think is anywhere clearly
stated in the book) is that we need collective investments in order to
stimulate forms of growth that are very different from those seen under
Neoliberal Informationalism. We need a government capable of shaping an
environment in which Commons-friendly investments will be possible. Yet
so far, not a single state has emerged as a reliable partner. I'm
curious: How do you feel about this today, Michel (and Vasilis), after
the difficulties that the FLOK project encountered in Ecuador, in the
attempt to generate exactly such a Partner State Approach?
The problems that our civilization faces are vast. The extension of
commons-based peer production from the software to manufacturing and
energy production does suggest a path forward. But support for it, in
the form of something like a Partner State, can only be generated from a
far broader civil-society movement than we have today. Such a movement
is being called into existence by the rising awareness that the current
form of development is literally a dead end. One one hand, it is
important to nurture this movement (and ourselves, as parts of it) with
pragmatic principles of hope, of the kind provided by experiments with
Commons-based peer production. On the other, it's necessary to cultivate
a very lucid of what's actually happening in society, not to paint an
apocalyptic picture but just to identify the really existing obstacles.
That kind of analysis is often lacking on the postmodern left. You could
have used a little more Trotsky and Mandel, imho.
I think that civil-society movements have a tremendous amount to learn
from experiments with peer production, and therefore, from the
reflections in the last third of this book. However, I don't think any
of this will go anywhere without a more realistic assessment of the
forces currently in play. A broad movement needs to know both what to
ask for and what to create, in view of pushing the really existing
political-economic system towards a fundamental structural change. That
means clearly facing the structure and power of corporate monopoly
capital in its transnational form. I feel you have dispatched that issue
too quickly and on that level, the book could definitely be improved.
Actually, a careful read of this book has left me with the desire to
rewrite parts of it, while keeping others intact - which I guess is a
pretty good outcome for a book that reccomends the use of Peer
Production Licenses!
Let me close this long review/letter with one more quote from Bauwens
and Kostakis, a particularly astute and admirable one:
"According to Brynjolfsson and McAfee (2011) 'When the changes happen
faster than expectations and/or institutions can adjust, the transition
can be cataclysmic.' To avoid such a cataclysm, we arguably need
political and social mobilization on the regional, national and
transnational scale, with a political agenda that would transform our
expectations, our economy, our infrastructures and our institutions in
the vein of a Commons-oriented political economy."
I could not agree more.
best, Brian
_______________________________________________
NetworkedLabour mailing list
NetworkedLabour at lists.contrast.org
http://lists.contrast.org/mailman/listinfo/networkedlabour
--
Check out the Commons Transition Plan here at:
http://en.wiki.floksociety.org/w/Research_Plan
P2P Foundation: http://p2pfoundation.net - http://blog.p2pfoundation.net
<http://lists.ourproject.org/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/p2p-foundation>Updates:
http://twitter.com/mbauwens; http://www.facebook.com/mbauwens
#82 on the (En)Rich list: http://enrichlist.org/the-complete-list/
-------------- next part --------------
An HTML attachment was scrubbed...
URL: https://lists.ourproject.org/pipermail/p2p-foundation/attachments/20141230/b202a5b1/attachment-0001.htm
More information about the P2P-Foundation
mailing list